二级建造师什么时候出成绩| 什么的恐龙| 7月1日是什么日子| 中国最高学位是什么| 前方高能是什么意思| cd20阳性什么意思| 心电图是什么科室| 脾胃虚弱吃什么中成药| 6月6是什么节日| 血小板高是什么意思| 阑尾炎挂号挂什么科| 纳呆是什么意思| 晚上尿多吃什么药| 腋臭和狐臭有什么区别| 急支糖浆是什么梗| 什么是贸易顺差| 率性是什么意思| 山楂有什么功效和作用| 清洁度1度是什么意思| 农历3月是什么月| 红色裤子搭配什么颜色上衣| 饶舌是什么意思| 什么是善良| 谷氨酸高是什么原因| 河蚌吃什么| 梦见女人是什么意思| 手掌很红是什么原因| 什么工作好| 腈纶是什么面料优缺点| 风土人情是什么意思| 邓紫棋为什么叫gem| 西游记主题曲叫什么| 心脏彩超可以检查什么| 抑郁症吃什么药最好| 掐人中有什么作用| 为什么一喝牛奶就拉肚子| 前庭是什么意思| 行了是什么意思| 净身出户是什么意思| 虾跟什么不能一起吃| 小鸭吃什么| 玉戴久了会有什么变化| 骑驴找马是什么意思| 梦见女人是什么意思| 今年流行什么颜色头发| 蝉什么时候出现| 老花眼视力模糊有什么办法解决吗| 甲亢病是什么原因引起的| cnb是什么意思| 怀孕为什么会流血| 皮肤过敏有什么妙招| 高铁为什么没有e| 藠头是什么菜| hisense什么牌子| 蒲公英的约定表达什么| 牛黄解毒片不能和什么药一起吃| 梦到狗是什么意思| 亲嘴会传染什么病| 手和脚发麻是什么原因| 总免疫球蛋白e是什么| 原研药是什么意思| 北极为什么没有企鹅| 什么的小莲蓬| 血清检查能测出什么| 3月26日是什么节日| 什么好| 周文王叫什么| 欣喜若狂是什么意思| 喝酒后头晕是什么原因| 牛肉炒什么菜| 菊花和金银花一起泡水有什么效果| 凭什么姐| 头晕出冷汗是什么原因| 8月24是什么星座| 2009年是什么年| 文房四宝指的是什么| 阴是什么意思| 什么地跑步| 老是掉发是什么原因| pet-ct检查主要检查什么| 哈尔滨机场叫什么名字| 预拌粉是什么东西| 农历五月二十是什么星座| 什么产品美白效果最好最快| 碘131是什么| 脚凉是什么原因造成的| 做梦梦见地震是什么意思| 正常白带什么样| 脚出汗用什么药| 子宫脱垂是什么症状| domyos是什么牌子| 月桂酰两性基乙酸钠是什么| 什么是甲沟炎图片| 立秋是什么时候| 基层是什么意思| 胃炎吃什么最好| 盆腔炎要做什么检查| 戌时右眼跳是什么预兆| 备孕需要做什么检查| 心跳过缓是什么原因造成的| 狗代表什么数字| 农历六月十八是什么星座| 检查免疫力都需要化验什么项目| 为什么不能摸猫的肚子| 胃食管反流吃什么中成药最好| 小哥哥是什么意思| 甲状腺吃什么药好| 为什么老是犯困| 什么人容易得老年痴呆| 细胞器是什么| 定妆喷雾什么时候用| 肩胛骨痛是什么原因| 疣是什么东西| 18k金是什么材质| 人体含量最多的元素是什么| 什么的怀抱| 什么的火焰| 擎什么意思| 记过处分有什么影响| 癞蛤蟆吃什么| 光屏是什么| 山药炖什么好吃| 什么啤酒好| 泻立停又叫什么名字| 牛拉稀用什么药最快| 梦见自己和别人结婚是什么意思| 三个金念什么| 什么路不能走| 鸡胸是什么病| 霜花店讲了什么故事| 蜜月是什么意思| 前途是什么意思| 套是什么意思| 日柱代表什么| 前列腺肥大吃什么药效果最好| 狻猊是什么动物| 经常长溃疡是什么原因引起的| 儿童水痘吃什么药| 深水炸弹什么意思| 胆囊炎吃什么药好得快| 做肺部ct挂什么科| 湿化瓶内放什么水| 女属蛇的和什么属相最配| 马不停蹄是什么生肖| 吃饱就犯困是什么原因| 血液由什么和什么组成| 急性尿道炎吃什么药| 精索静脉曲张有什么症状| 投喂是什么意思| 肝掌是什么样子| 痛经是什么| 做生意的人最忌讳什么| 嗪读什么| 23年属什么生肖| 嘴唇边缘发黑是什么原因| 什么水果对肠胃好| 空囊是什么意思| 熊猫为什么吃竹子| 梦到蛇什么意思| art是什么意思| 自古红颜多薄命是什么意思| 空调外机风扇不转是什么原因| 肾衰竭是什么意思| 家贼是什么生肖| 什么时候不容易怀孕| 蚊子怕什么气味| 白头发补什么维生素| force是什么牌子| 阴道恶臭是什么原因| 香精是什么| 扬州瘦马什么意思| 肾炎康复片主要是治疗什么| 吃饭肚子疼是什么原因| 一黑一白是什么蛇| 龙井茶是什么茶| 做梦梦到拉屎是什么意思| 紫绀是什么症状| 乐得什么填词语| 心功能一级什么意思| gl小说是什么意思| 磨砂膏是什么| 口水歌是什么意思| 成长是什么| 肚子很硬是什么原因| 为什么叫犹太人| 鱼生是什么鱼| 周易和易经有什么区别| 大千世界什么意思| 诺迪康胶囊治什么病| 哥伦比亚牌子什么档次| 月经一直不停有什么办法止血| 纳米是什么| 银色的什么| 身份证号码最后一位代表什么| 孕妇口腔溃疡能用什么药| 乳腺穿刺是什么意思| 巨人观是什么意思| 淋巴结转移是什么意思| 孕妇喝什么牛奶| 人生格言是什么意思| 草字头一个见念什么| 喝什么汤下奶最快最多| 陕西八大怪是什么| 心肌缺血是什么原因引起的| 三点水加个有字念什么| 什么是考生号| 霉菌是什么菌| 防字代表什么生肖| 什么什么大什么| 颠覆三观是什么意思| 肾囊肿是什么原因引起的| 黄体酮吃了有什么副作用| 什么是半月板损伤| 早搏什么症状| 术前四项检查是什么| 功课是什么意思| 什么是收缩压和舒张压| 飞刃是什么意思| 报捕是什么意思| 狐臭是什么原因引起的| 五险一金和社保有什么区别| 锁骨中间的窝叫什么| 血压低有什么办法| 微信屏蔽是什么意思| 闽南语懒觉是什么意思| 十一月什么星座| 自省是什么意思| 催乳素过高会有什么严重的后果| 尿气味很重是什么原因| 树菠萝什么时候成熟| 天公作美是什么生肖| 拥趸是什么意思| 京畿是什么意思| 生吃西红柿有什么好处| 绿本是什么| 得了阴虱用什么药能除根| 菠菜和豆腐为什么不能一起吃| 黑加仑是什么水果| 员级职称是什么意思| 手指麻木什么原因| 眼皮痒是什么原因| 扁桃体发炎严重吃什么药好得快| 北宋六贼为什么没高俅| 女人得性疾病什么症状| 玫瑰糠疹是什么原因引起的| 单侧耳鸣是什么原因引起的| 肺寒咳嗽吃什么药| 下午头晕是什么原因引起的| 半边脸疼是什么原因引起的| 生殖疱疹用什么药效果好| 塞翁失马是什么意思| 尿里有泡沫是什么原因| 牒是什么意思| 大红袍属于什么档次| 晚上蝴蝶来家什么预兆| 什么是焦虑症| 鼓刹和碟刹有什么区别| 夜尿频多吃什么药效果好| 移植后吃什么容易着床| 57年的鸡是什么命| 宝宝拉水便是什么原因| 干什么| 梦到手机丢了什么预兆| 手肘黑是什么原因| 百度Jump to content

人民日报看河南--河南频道--人民网

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
百度 “棍下出孝子”并非家教的正确方式东方网武西奇王永娟  1月5日,泰州泰兴黄桥发生一起悲剧,因9岁(实则8周岁)儿子犯错,母亲在教育孩子时失手将其打死。

The right to property, or the right to own property (cf. ownership), is often[how often?] classified as a human right for natural persons regarding their possessions. A general recognition of a right to private property is found[citation needed] more rarely and is typically heavily constrained insofar as property is owned by legal persons (i.e. corporations) and where it is used for production rather than consumption.[1][need quotation to verify] The Fourth Amendment to the United States Constitution is credited as a significant precedent for the legal protection of individual property rights.

A right to property is specified in Article 17 of the 1948 Universal Declaration of Human Rights,[2] but it is not recognised in the 1966 International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights or in the 1966 International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights.[3] The 1950 European Convention on Human Rights acknowledges a right for a natural or legal person to "peaceful enjoyment of his possessions", subject to the "general interest or to secure the payment of taxes."[4]

Definition

[edit]

The right to property is one of the most controversial human rights, both in terms of its existence and interpretation. The controversy about the definition of the right meant that it was not included in the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights or the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights.[3] Controversy centres upon who is deemed to have property rights protected (e.g. human beings or also corporations), the type of property which is protected (property used for the purpose of consumption or production) and the reasons for which property can be restricted (for instance, for regulations, taxation or nationalisation in the public interest). In all human rights instruments, either implicit or express restrictions exist on the extent to which property is protected. Article 17 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (UDHR) enshrines the right to property as follows:

(1) Everyone has the right to own property alone as well as in association with others. (2) No one shall be arbitrarily deprived of his or her property.[5]

The object of the right to property as it is usually understood nowadays consists of property already owned or possessed, or of property acquired or to be acquired by a person through lawful means. Not in opposition but in contrast to this, some proposals also defend a universal right to private property, in the sense of a right of every person to effectively receive a certain amount of property, grounded in a claim to Earth's natural resources or other theories of justice.[6]

Africa

[edit]

The African Charter on Human and Peoples' Rights (ACHPR) protects the right to property most explicitly in Article 14,[7] stating:

The right to property shall be guaranteed. It may only be encroached upon in the interest of public need or in the general interest of the community and in accordance with the provisions of appropriate laws.[8]

Property rights are furthermore recognised in Article 13 of the ACHPR, which states that every citizen has the right to participate freely in the government of his country, the right to equal access to public services and "the right of access to public property and services in strict equality of all persons before the law". Article 21 of the ACHPR recognises the right of all peoples to freely dispose of their wealth and natural resources and that this right shall be exercised in the exclusive interest of the people, who may not be deprived of this right. Article 21 also provides that "in case of spoliation the dispossessed people shall have the right to the lawful recovery of its property as well as to adequate compensation".[9]

Americas

[edit]

When the text of the UDHR was negotiated, other states in the Americas argued that the right to property should be limited to the protection of private property necessary for subsistence. Their suggestion was opposed, but was enshrined in the American Declaration of the Rights and Duties of Man, which was negotiated at the same time and adopted one year before the UDHR in 1948.[10] Article 23 of the declaration states:

Every Person has the right to own such private property as meets the essential needs of decent living and helps to maintain the dignity of the individual and of the home.[11]

The definition of the right to property is heavily influenced by Western concepts of property rights, but because property rights vary considerably in different legal systems it has not been possible to establish international standards on property rights.[12] The regional human rights instruments of Europe, Africa and the Americas recognise the right to protection of property to varying degrees.[13]

The American Convention on Human Rights (ACHR) recognises the right to protection of property, including the right to "just compensation". The ACHR also prohibits usury and other exploitation, which is unique amongst human rights instruments.[10] Article 21 of the ACHR states:

(1) Everyone has the right to the use and enjoyment of his property. The law may subordinate such use and enjoyment to the interest of society.

(2) No one shall be deprived of his property except upon payment of just compensation, for reasons of public utility or social interest, and in the cases and according to the forms established by law.

(3) Usury and any other form of exploitation of man by man shall be prohibited by law.[14]

Europe

[edit]

After failed attempts to include the right to protection of property in the European Convention on Human Rights (ECHR), European states enshrined the right to protection of property in Article 1 of Protocol I to the ECHR as the "right to peaceful enjoyment of possessions",[15] where the right to protection of property is defined as such:

(1) Every natural or legal person is entitled to the peaceful enjoyment of his possessions. No one shall be deprived of his possessions except in the public interest and subject to the conditions provided for by law and by the general principles of international law. (2) The preceding provisions shall not, however, in any way impair the right of a State to enforce such laws as it deems necessary to control the use of property in accordance with the general interest or to secure the payment of taxes or other contributions or penalties.[16]

Therefore, European human rights law recognises the right to peaceful enjoyment of property, makes deprivation of possessions subject to certain conditions and recognises that states can balance the right to peaceful possession of property against the public interest. The European Court of Human Rights has interpreted "possessions" to include not only tangible property, but also economic interests, contractual agreements with economic value, compensation claims against the state and public law related claims such as pensions.[17] The European Court of Human Rights has held that the right to property is not absolute and states have a wide degree of discretion to limit the rights. As such, the right to property is regarded as a more flexible right than other human rights. States' degree of discretion is defined in Handyside v. United Kingdom, heard by the European Court of Human Rights in 1976. Notable cases where the European Court of Human Rights has found the right to property having been violated include Sporrong and Lonnroth v. Sweden, heard in 1982, where Swedish law kept property under the threat of expropriation for an extended period of time.[3] The highest economic compensation following a judgment of the Strasbourg Court on this matter was given (1,3 million euro) in case Beyeler v. Italy.[18]

India

[edit]

In India property rights (Article 31) was one of the fundamental rights of citizens until 1978, and it became a legal right through the 44th Amendment to the Constitution in 1978.[19] The amendment was introduced by the Morarji Desai government as part of land reform policies.[19] In 2020, the Supreme Court of India has stated that, even though property rights are not part of a citizen's fundamental right, it should be considers as one of the human rights promised by the Constitution.[19][20] The Supreme Court also ruled that the states cannot acquire individual land unless there is a clear legal framework.[19]

International conventions

[edit]

Property rights are also recognised in the International Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Racial Discrimination which states in Article 5 that everyone has the right to equality before the law without distinction as to race, colour and national or ethnic origin, including the "right to own property alone as well as in association with others" and "the right to inherit". The Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women recognises the property rights in Article 16, which establishes the same right for both spouses to ownership, acquisition, management, administration, enjoyment and disposition of property and Article 15, which establishes women's right to conclude contracts.[7]

Property rights are also enshrined in the Convention Relating to the Status of Refugees and the Convention on the Protection of the Rights of All Migrant Workers and Members of Their Families. These international human rights instruments for minorities do not establish a separate right to property, but prohibit discrimination in relation to property rights where such rights are guaranteed.[21]

Relationship to other rights

[edit]

The right to private property was a crucial demand in early quests for political freedom and equality and against feudal control of property. Property can serve as the basis for the entitlements that ensure the realisation of the right to an adequate standard of living and it was only property owners which were initially granted civil and political rights, such as the right to vote. Because not everybody is a property owner, the right to work was enshrined to allow everybody to attain an adequate standard of living.[22] Today, discrimination on the basis of property ownership is commonly seen as a serious threat to the equal enjoyment of human rights by all and non-discrimination clauses in international human rights instruments frequently include property as a ground on the basis of which discrimination is prohibited (see the right to equality before the law).[7] The protection of private property may come into conflict with economic, social and cultural rights and civil and political rights, such as the right to freedom of expression. To mitigate this, the right to property is commonly limited to protect the public interest. Many states also maintain systems of communal and collective ownership. Property rights have frequently been regarded as preventing the realisation of human rights for all, through for example slavery and the exploitation of others. Unequal distribution of wealth often follows line of sex, race and minorities, therefore property rights may appear to be part of the problem, rather than as an interest that merits protection. Property rights have been at the centre of recent human rights debates on land reform, the return of cultural artifacts by collectors and museums to indigenous peoples and the popular sovereignty of peoples over natural resources.[23]

History

[edit]

The Roman law defined property as "the right to use and abuse one's own within the limits of the law" — jus utendi et abutendi re sua, guatenus juris ratio patitur. Second, salus populi suprema lex esto, or "the safety of the people shall be the supreme law," was stipulated as early as the Law of the Twelve Tables. The notion of private property and property rights was elaborated further in the Renaissance as international trade by merchants gave rise to mercantilist ideas. In 16th-century Europe, Lutheranism and the Protestant Reformation advanced property rights using biblical terminology. The Protestant work ethic and views on man's destiny came to underline social views in emerging capitalist economies in early modern Europe. The right to private property emerged as a radical demand for human rights vis-a-vis the state in 17th-century revolutionary Europe, but in the 18th and 19th centuries the right to property as a human right became subject of intense controversy.[24]

English Civil War

[edit]

The arguments advanced by the Levellers during the English Civil War on property and civil and political rights, such as the right to vote, informed subsequent debates in other countries.[citation needed] The Levellers emerged as a political movement in mid-17th century England in the aftermath of the Protestant Reformation. They believed that property which had been earned as the fruit of one's labour was sacred under the Bible's commandment "thou shall not steal". As such, they believed that the right to acquire property from one's work was sacred. Levellers' views on the right to property and the right not to be deprived of property as a civil and political right were developed by the pamphleteer Richard Overton.[25] In "An Arrow against all Tyrants" (1646), Overton argued:

To every individual in nature is given an individual property by nature not to be invaded or usurped by any. For everyone, as he is himself, so he has a self propertiety, else he could not be himself; and of this no second may presume to deprive of without manifest violation and affront to the very principles of nature of the rules of equity and justice between man and man. Mine and thine cannot be, except this. No man has power over my rights and liberties, and I over no man.[26]

The views of the Levellers, who enjoyed support amongst small-scale property-owners and craftsmen, were not shared by all revolutionary parties of the English Civil War. At the 1647 General Council, Oliver Cromwell and Henry Ireton argued against equating the right to life with the right to property. They argued that doing so would establish the right to take anything that one may want, irrespective of the rights of others. The Leveller Thomas Rainsborough responded, relying on Overton's arguments, that the Levellers required respect for others' natural rights. The definition of property and whether it was acquired as the fruit of one's labour and as such a natural right was subject to intense debate because the right to vote depended on property ownership. Political freedom was at the time associated with property ownership and individual independence. Cromwell and Ireton maintained that only property in freehold land or chartered trading rights gave a man the right to vote. They argued that this type of property ownership constituted a "stake in society", which entitles men to political power. In contrast, Levellers argued that all men who are not servants, alms-recipients or beggars should be considered as property owners and be given voting rights. They believed that political freedom could only be secured by individuals, such as craftsmen, engaging in independent economic activity.[25][27]

Levellers were primarily concerned with the civil and political rights of small-scale property owners and workers, whereas the Diggers, a smaller revolutionary group led by Gerrard Winstanley, focused on the rights of the rural poor who worked on landed property. The Diggers argued that private property was not consistent with justice and that the land that had been confiscated from the Crown and Church should be turned into communal land to be cultivated by the poor. According to the Diggers, the right to vote should be extended to all and everybody had the right to an adequate standard of living. With the Restoration of the English monarchy in 1660, all confiscated land returned to the Crown and Church. Some property rights were recognised and limited voting rights were established. The ideas of the Levellers on property and civil and political rights remained influential and were advanced in the subsequent 1688 Glorious Revolution,[25][27] but restrictions on the right to vote based on property meant that only a fraction of the British population had the suffrage. In 1780 only 214,000 property-owning men were entitled to vote in England and Wales, less than 3 percent of the population of 8 million. The Reform Act 1832 restricted the right to vote to men who owned property with an annual value of £10, giving approximately 4 percent of the adult male population the right to vote. The reforms of 1867 extended the right to vote to approximately 8 percent. The working class (which increased dramatically with the Industrial Revolution) and industrialists remained effectively excluded from the political system.[28][29]

John Locke and the American and French revolutions

[edit]
John Locke's 1689 Two Treatises of Government in which Locke calls "lives, liberties and estates" the "property" of individuals

The English philosopher John Locke (1632–1704) developed the ideas of property, civil and political rights further. In his Second Treatise on Civil Government (1689), Locke proclaimed that "everyman has a property in his person; this nobody has a right to but himself. The labor of his body and the work of his hand, we may say, are properly his".[30] He argued that property ownership derives from one's labor, though those who do not own property and only have their labor to sell should not be given the same political power as those who owned property. Labourers, small-scale property owners and large-scale property owners should have civil and political rights in proportion to the property they owned. According to Locke, the right to property and the right to life were inalienable rights and that it was the duty of the state to secure these rights for individuals. Locke argued that the safeguarding of natural rights, such as the right to property, along with the separation of powers and other checks and balances, would help to curtail political abuses by the state.[25][31]

Locke's labor theory of property and the separation of powers greatly influenced the American Revolution and the French Revolution. The entitlement to civil and political rights, such as the right to vote, was tied to the question of property in both revolutions. American revolutionaries, such as Benjamin Franklin and Thomas Jefferson, opposed universal suffrage, advocating votes only for those who owned a "stake" in society. James Madison argued that extending the right to vote to all could lead in the right to property and justice being "overruled by a majority without property". While it was initially suggested[by whom?] to establish the right to vote for all men, eventually the right to vote in the nascent United States was extended to white men who owned a specified amount of real estate and personal property.

French revolutionaries recognised property rights in Article 17 of the Declaration of the Rights of Man and of the Citizen (1791), which stated that no one "may be deprived of property rights unless a legally established public necessity required it and upon condition of a just and previous indemnity". Articles 3 and 6 declared that "all citizens have the right to contribute personally or through their representatives" in the political system and that "all citizens being equal before [the law], are equally admissible to all public offices, positions and employment according to their capacity, and without other distinction than that of virtues and talents". However, in practice the French revolutionaries did not extend civil and political rights to all, although the property qualification required for such rights was lower than that established by the American revolutionaries.[32]

According to the French revolutionary Abbé Sieyès, "all the inhabitants of a country should enjoy the right of a passive citizen... but those alone who contribute to the public establishment are like the true shareholders in the great social enterprise. They alone are the true active citizens, the true members of the association". Three months after the Declaration had been adopted, domestic servants, women and those who did not pay taxes equal to three days of labor were declared "passive citizens". Sieyes wanted to see the rapid expansion of commercial activities and favoured the unrestricted accumulation of property. In contrast, Maximilien Robespierre warned that the free accumulation of wealth ought to be limited and that the right to property should not be permitted to violate the rights of others, particularly poorer citizens, including the working poor and peasants. Robespierre's views were eventually excluded from the French Constitution of 1793 and a property qualification for civil and political rights was maintained.[33]

See also

[edit]

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ See generally Berle, Adolph A. (1965). "Property, Production and Revolution". Columbia Law Review. 65 (1): 1–20. doi:10.2307/1120512. JSTOR 1120512.
  2. ^ "Universal Declaration of Human Rights". un.org. Article 17. 1) Everyone has the right to own property alone as well as in association with others.
  3. ^ a b c Doebbler, Curtis F. J. (2006). Introduction to International Human Rights Law. CD Publishing. pp. 141–142. ISBN 978-0-9743570-2-7.
  4. ^ European Convention on Human Rights, protocol 1, article 1
  5. ^ "Universal Declaration of Human Rights". United Nations. Article 17.
  6. ^ Stilman, Gabriel. "La Biblia, Laudato Si y el derecho universal a la propiedad privada". El Dial – Biblioteca Jurídica online. Retrieved 2 February 2016.
  7. ^ a b c Alfredsson & Eide (1999), p. 372.
  8. ^ "African Charter on Human and Peoples' Rights". Organisation of African Unity. Article 14.
  9. ^ "African Charter on Human and Peoples' Rights". Organisation of African Unity. pp. Article 13 and 21.
  10. ^ a b Alfredsson & Eide (1999), p. 370.
  11. ^ "American Declaration of the Rights and Duties of Man". Ninth International Conference of American States. Article 23.
  12. ^ Alfredsson & Eide (1999), pp. 359–360.
  13. ^ Alfredsson & Eide (1999), p. 364.
  14. ^ "American Convention on Human Rights". Organization of American States. Article 21.
  15. ^ Alfredsson & Eide (1999), p. 366.
  16. ^ "Protocol I to the Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms". Council of Europe. pp. Protocol 1 Article 1.
  17. ^ Alfredsson & Eide (1999), p. 367.
  18. ^ The handling of the affair by the Italian authorities has never been the most mirrored, although it is clear that, in the case Beyeler, the right and wrong was not all on one side: Buonomo, Giampiero (2002). "Il contribuente paga il conto dell'adeguamento ai principi di legalità e buona amministrazione". Diritto&Giustizia Edizione Online. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  19. ^ a b c d ?????????, ?????. "??????????? ????????????; ?????? ??????? ??????? ????? ????????????????". Mathrubhumi (in Malayalam).
  20. ^ "??????????? ?????? ??????? ?????? : ????????????". Deshabhimani (in Malayalam).
  21. ^ Alfredsson & Eide (1999), p. 373.
  22. ^ Alfredsson & Eide (1999), p. 533.
  23. ^ Alfredsson & Eide (1999), p. 360.
  24. ^ Compare: Ishay (2008), pp. 91
  25. ^ a b c d Ishay (2008), pp. 91–94.
  26. ^ Ishay (2008), pp. 92.
  27. ^ a b Rossides, Daniel W. (1998). Social Theory: Its Origins, History, and Contemporary Relevance. Rowman & Littlefield. p. 54. ISBN 978-1-882289-50-9.
  28. ^ Robinson, Eric W. (2004). Ancient Greek democracy: readings and sources. Wiley-Blackwell. p. 302. ISBN 978-0-631-23394-7.
  29. ^ "The Struggle for democracy – Getting the vote". National archives. Retrieved 15 January 2011.
  30. ^ Second Treatise of Civil Government, § 27
  31. ^ Rossides, Daniel W. (1998). Social Theory: Its Origins, History, and Contemporary Relevance. Rowman & Littlefield. pp. 52–54. ISBN 978-1-882289-50-9.
  32. ^ Ishay (2008), pp. 94–97.
  33. ^ Ishay (2008), pp. 97–98.

References

[edit]
[edit]
煮牛肉放什么料 尿泡沫多吃什么药 孕期心情不好对胎儿有什么影响 非萎缩性胃炎吃什么药效果好 梦见狗咬人是什么预兆
女人肾阴虚吃什么药 跨境电子商务是什么 白眼狼是什么意思 夏天吃什么蔬菜 晚上吃什么饭
脚气是什么菌 牙齿脱矿是什么原因 血压高吃什么药好 股市xd是什么意思 loa是什么胎位
白细胞减少有什么症状 日本人为什么喜欢喝冰水 罡是什么意思 化合物是什么 喜欢吃肉的动物是什么生肖
飞机杯长什么样子hcv9jop5ns3r.cn 前列腺炎是什么hcv9jop1ns7r.cn 艾滋病窗口期是什么意思hcv9jop4ns9r.cn 梅花代表什么象征意义hcv8jop1ns1r.cn 狮子座跟什么星座最配hcv8jop9ns6r.cn
脸上长白斑是什么原因引起的hcv8jop4ns5r.cn 周期是什么hcv9jop4ns0r.cn 宝宝便秘吃什么hcv8jop1ns4r.cn 血去掉一撇念什么hcv8jop4ns4r.cn 前列腺特异性抗原高是什么原因hcv9jop3ns6r.cn
心衰吃什么药好adwl56.com 碧文圆顶是什么意思hcv9jop1ns9r.cn 科目三为什么这么难hcv9jop7ns1r.cn 6.20是什么星座hcv8jop3ns2r.cn 嫩模是什么意思hcv7jop7ns4r.cn
晚上睡觉脚底发热是什么原因hcv9jop5ns3r.cn ctu是什么意思hcv8jop7ns9r.cn 犀利的眼神是什么意思hcv9jop1ns0r.cn 什么叫环比hcv7jop5ns2r.cn 什么是实性结节hkuteam.com
百度